Download PDF The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent

By Agustus 29, 2017

Download PDF The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent

By going to the web link, you could make the manage the site to get the soft data. Ever mind, there is no distinction in between this sort of soft documents book and the published publication. It will distinguish only in the kinds. And also what you will certainly likewise acquire from The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent soft data is that it will show you ways to live your life, ways to improve your life, as well as ways to guide to be much better.

The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent

The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent


The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent


Download PDF The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent

The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent How an easy idea by reading can improve you to be a successful individual? Reviewing The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent is a quite simple activity. However, just how can many individuals be so careless to read? They will certainly choose to invest their free time to talking or socializing. When actually, reviewing The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent will certainly provide you much more possibilities to be successful finished with the hard works.

Not only from the nation, have people around the world liked this book so much. They are the fantastic individuals, people who constantly have readiness as well as spirit to read and boost their skill as well as knowledge. Will you be one of the? Definitely, when you are relay curious about, you can be among the fantastic individuals. This The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent is presented to attract you because it is so basic to recognize. Yet, the meaning is so deep. You could feel like dealing with and also acting on your own.

From the title, we will certainly likewise reveal you the topic pertaining to describe. When you in fact require this kind of source, why don't you take it currently? This book will certainly not just offer you the expertise and lesson about the topic, from words that are made use of, it specify new fun point. This The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent will certainly make you feel no fear to spend even more time in analysis.

Be the very first to download this book The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent and allow checked out by coating. It is really easy to read this book The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent due to the fact that you do not have to bring this published The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent everywhere. Your soft documents book can be in our gadget or computer so you could take pleasure in reviewing almost everywhere and also each time if needed. This is why great deals varieties of people likewise read the books The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent in soft fie by downloading guide. So, be one of them that take all advantages of reviewing guide The Wealth Of Humans: Work, Power, And Status In The Twenty-first Century, By Ryan Avent by on the internet or on your soft documents system.

The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent

Review

“Ryan Avent is a superb writer. I am confident that his book will be very successful.”―Thomas Piketty“Ryan Avent is one of the sharpest and most intelligent writers around. Nobody is better placed to tell us how technology is shaping our economy and our lives.”―Tim Harford“Many of the world's top economists read, engage with, and debate Ryan Avent on a regular basis, including on labor markets and technology.” ―Tyler Cowen“An ambitious, insightful and provocative book...Avent ranges widely through the often insular silos of economics, blending microeconomics with macro, industrial organization with international trade, labor economics with financial, economic history with economic geography. In the best Economist tradition, this book is both accessible and sophisticated, one that raises all the right questions.”―Washington Post

Read more

About the Author

RYAN AVENT is an economics correspondent for the Economist. He's also the primary contributor to its Free Exchange blog and a contributor to The New York Times, The Washington Post, The New Republic, The Atlantic, and The Guardian, among other publications. He is the author of a Kindle Single: The Gated City, which analyzes migration from American cities. Avent was previously an economic consultant and an industry analyst for the Bureau of Labor Statistics. He lives in London, England. The Wealth of Humans is his first book.

Read more

Product details

Hardcover: 288 pages

Publisher: St. Martin's Press (September 20, 2016)

Language: English

ISBN-10: 1250075807

ISBN-13: 978-1250075802

Product Dimensions:

6.4 x 1 x 9.6 inches

Shipping Weight: 1 pounds (View shipping rates and policies)

Average Customer Review:

4.4 out of 5 stars

35 customer reviews

Amazon Best Sellers Rank:

#608,057 in Books (See Top 100 in Books)

While I found the book easy to read, apparently well researched, and reasonably well organized, what follows is more of a summary of the book's key ideas than a critique of them. There's a number of useful reviews here, especially those by other economists with alternative viewpoints; I encourage you to read them for a more informed critique.In most economically free societies, the two mechanisms of wealth-sharing are work (employers shift wealth to employees by paying them) and redistribution (taxes pay for goods and services that may not be redistributed in proportion to how much you paid), and the society has a definition of who is "in" (eligible to participate in both mechanisms). This book asks: What happens to these mechanisms when increasing automation is squeezing the first, and those controlling the wealth are opposed to expanding the reach of the second?Its overall responses are: (1) while it's true that policy everywhere has tipped to favor wealth concentration, the essential problem is structural; (2) As a result of this fundamental structural problem, most efforts to "create jobs" will run into problems that ultimately doom them; (3) therefore, for better or worse, some form of non-labor-based redistribution will become necessary (eg universal basic income).1. PRODUCTIVITY-ENHANCING TECHNOLOGY CAN WORK AGAINST A BALANCED LABOR MARKETHenry Ford's innovation was to de-skill individual roles to vastly decrease the cost and increase the per-employee productivity of making cars; precisely because the de-skilled jobs were tedious, he raised wages and coddled his employees to attract labor and reduce turnover, something he could afford to do because of their high productivity. But this scenario comes with 3 problems.First, the high productivity makes it affordable to pay higher wages, but workers in low-productivity industries such as education and healthcare that suffer from Baumol's "cost disease" (it costs about the same to educate 1 student or care for 1 patient as it ever has) are in the same labor market, so their wages must rise *despite* stagnant productivity, thereby increasing the cost to the consumer of purchasing those goods or services. That is, wealthy companies can afford to pay employees more because of the employees' much higher productivity, so that most income inequality is due to wage gaps *between* firms/sectors rather than within them.Second, productivity-enhancing de-skilling paves the way for complete automation of those jobs, so the benefit to low-skill workers is short-lived.Third, since higher productivity leads to a labor glut even before automation takes over, it pushes wages down. This is bad because while the effective price of some goods also falls due to that productivity (cars, cell phones), the effective price of others doesn't, either because supply is scarce (housing) or because they suffer from Baumol's cost disease of stagnant productivity (education, healthcare).This is an example of how "job creation" systems can end up working against themselves. Future employment opportunities will likely satisfy at most 2 of the following 3 conditions ("employment trilemma"): (1) high productivity and wages, (2) resistant to automation, (3) potential to absorb large amounts of labor. To see the dynamic, consider the solar-panel industry. Increased productivity in manufacturing solar panels has caused them to drop in cost, creating a large market for solar panel installers, a job resistant to automation (meets criteria 2 and 3). But that same increased productivity means most of the cost of acquiring solar is the installation labor, limiting wage growth for installers (fails criterion 1). As another example, consider healthcare. As technology increases the productivity of (or automates) other aspects of care delivery, healthcare jobs will concentrate in non-automatable services requiring few skills besides bedside manner and the willingness to do basic and often unpleasant caregiver tasks. As a third, consider artisanally-produced goods, whose low productivity is part of their appeal (meets 1 and 2). But the market for them is limited to the small subset of people who can afford to buy them (fails 3).Can education help? Higher educational attainment is still key to high wages, but not to high wage *growth*. The level of education required for that has been climbing higher and higher, putting it beyond the economic (and possibly intellectual) reach of most people, yet those are precisely the credentials needed to participate in the most lucrative parts of the economy. The displaced workers "trickle down" the skill-level chain and depress wages even higher in the wage hierarchy. So improving education, while a good idea, won't help people in poor countries as much as simply moving them into a rich country to work in that economy.2. HENCE, SOCIAL CAPITAL IS INCREASINGLY KEY TO SUCCESSFUL COMPANIES AND SOCIETIESSince WW2, developed-nation economies have increasingly "dematerialized" to where most of the value in goods being produced was in knowledge-worker contributions, rather than physical manufacturing or the labor therein. (iPhones and cars are built overseas, yet most of their value is in design and software, which aren't outsourced.) Increasingly, the "wealth" of a company is not in its capitalization or even the material output of its employees, but its "culture" -- its way of absorbing, refactoring, and acting on information in a value-added way that is difficult to replicate and produces a product customers want to buy.(This is also why cities are resurgent -- they permit a dense social/living fabric that promotes evolution of social capital, and the larger/denser the city, the more productive it becomes because of this effect, supporting high levels of specialization and social networks that facilitate labor mobility. The demand results in high housing costs, but NIMBYs oppose building more housing because even though the benefits would be spread over the whole city, the costs would be concentrated in their neighborhood.)By definition, culture is a group phenomenon, not a set of rules handed down by a boss. Social capital cannot be exported like material goods; all you can do is try to create (or impose) conditions under which it can develop by allowing the free flow of ideas and labor (ie, the people in whose heads social capital lives), as the EU is trying to do within Europe. This is troubling for developing economies whose societies lack social capital.Hence, China, having spent a fortune to create physical infrastructure to improve worker productivity, has reached diminishing returns: further productivity improvements must now come from "deepening" the workers' social capital, which has been wrecked by decades of cultural mismanagement by a totalitarian regime. Similarly, India's outsourcing boom and China's hyper-rapid industrialization occurred because technology allowed them to temporarily bypass the difficult step of building social capital, by "biting off" chunks of activity taking place in richer economies: India hosting outsourced call centers, or China jumping into a global supply chain established by rich economies and uniquely facilitated by the digital economy, in both cases offering labor at lower cost. But this era is ending: other countries can play the same trick (eg Indonesia as the new China, depressing Chinese wages), automation is coming, and the relative advantage to outsourcing decreases as products become more information-centric. (Though note that while "reshoring" is happening, it's not creating more jobs: Tesla would rather pay a few highly skilled engineers to oversee an automated assembly plant than pay lots of low-skilled factory workers to build something manually and less reliably elsewhere.)It used to be thought that poor countries were poor because they lacked financial capital, but it's now clear that they can build factories without resulting in good social capital (India, China). Indeed, highly-educated workers in poor countries become more productive when they move to rich countries, suggesting it's the country's social capital that is lacking.3. YET BENEFITS OF SOCIAL CAPITAL DON'T ACCRUE TO THOSE WHO EMBODY ITYet as important as social capital is, when a worker leaves a company, his knowledge of that company's "culture" is generally not useful at a new firm, so he has little leverage (though this is somewhat counterbalanced by the pressure to not have *most* workers quit, which would destroy the culture). Conversely, a chief executive is harder and costlier to replace, so has more leverage as an individual. Herein lies the problem: "social capital" is in the collective heads of individual workers, but its benefits flow disproportionately to the owners of financial capital. A corollary is that the efficiency gains achieved by fluid (ie non-unionized) labor markets haven't been redistributed to the workers whose bargaining power was sacrificed to achieve those efficiencies. Marx predicted that that dynamic was unsustainable, and the society would collapse because either the workers would revolt and upend the government and the social norms it curates, hence destroying the wealth for everyone, or that the wealth-owners would asymptotically reach a point where no further wealth could be generated and harvested so they'd start fighting each other over the fixed amount of wealth, again destroying the society. Piketty notes that the 2 world wars did a lot to disrupt this downward slide because wars, taxation, inflation, and depression destroyed many of the superconcentrated fortunes made in the industrial age, but as noted above, the change was temporary.The consequence of this structural problem is that some form of non-labor-based redistribution is likely to be the only nonviolent way forward. This path has at least two challenges. One is that the act of doing work has other benefits -- agency, dignity, reinforcement of socially-useful values -- that would be lost; although surveys show that people saddled with extra free time due to weak job markets tend to spend it sleeping or watching TV, ie, at leisure. A second challenge is that such "highly redistributive" societies tend to emerge in ethnically/nationally coherent political units, and motivate the society to draw a tight boundary around itself. E.g. Scandinavian countries have generous welfare states that make them desirable to immigrate into, but as a result the load on the welfare system generated by lots of immigration is tearing at the seams of their welfare economies. That is, we can't expect rich liberal countries to throw open their borders heedlessly when the potential pool of immigrants dwarfs those working to generate the wealth that is redistributed.

Ryan Avent's book is an ambitious summary of recent economic trends and possible future economic trends affecting the labor market. His perspective is pessimistic. He believes that technological changes are reducing demand for labor to well-below available labor supply, which will lead either to widespread non-employment or low wages for much of the population. Avent believes that education will help, but is insufficient. The real solution, in his view, involves significantly increasing redistribution, for example through a basic income. However, such redistribution will be difficult to accomplish, largely for political reasons. In the end, despite all this, Avent seems to believe that we will somehow figure out how to accomplish the needed redistribution while continuing to expand the overall economic pie through technological progress.As a labor and regional economist, I disagree with much of Avent's argument. I think Avent overstates how much increased inequality is due to inevitable forces of technological change, and understates how much is due to "institutional" or political changes, for example the decline in the power of unions. I also think he understates the potential adaptation of labor demand to available labor supply. If public policy decides that we want to significantly increase the quality of infrastructure, education, and health care, this can significantly augment labor demand, and alleviate the demand/supply imbalance. If such labor demand policies are combined with increasing job skills, and institutional changes to push up wages (e.g., unionization, higher minimum wages), then the problems described by Avent will be much alleviated.However, despite my hesitations about Avent's analysis of the problem, and proposed solutions, I strongly recommend the book. Why? (1) He describes the scope of the labor market inequality problem in s a clear way, which alone is worth the price of the book. (2) His particular perspective represents one scenario for what could happen, which, although not inevitable in my view, is certainly a plausible future course. (3) I think his pessimism is frightening enough that it should encourage people to think boldly about possible alternatives. We need that spur to action.

A thoughtful analysis on the future of labor. I found it to be an interesting and even eloquent read. However, I agree with other reviewers: there are insufficient recommendations on how to deal with the effects of the coming abundance of labor.

No deep analysis on the formation or deformation of poltical power but good for an editior of economist to have a pragmatic critique to neo liberalism.

Comprehensive, well-argumented treatment of a challenging theme - difficult to disagree on anything

This book delves into the most important phenomena affecting today's and tomorrow's employment prospects.From hyper globalization, ineffective monetary policy to artificial intelligence, this book examines the forces driving the actual and expected labor glut.Conventional redistribution policies could prove to be tricky and harmuful. New social and economic models will have to be invented.For those who want a non linear and historical approach to the subject, this book will not let you down.

Avent writes with clarity and great style. I have serious concerns about anyone who says this book is not worth reading.

Well worth the read, but a read that requires being re-read to fully grasp many of the complex economic and social issues discussed within. The subject is broad and the author attempts to boil it down into digestible bites for the non-economics major. He does this with mixed success. Again, the work is deserving of a second reading to fully appreciate its valuable insights.

The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent PDF
The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent EPub
The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent Doc
The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent iBooks
The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent rtf
The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent Mobipocket
The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent Kindle

The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent PDF

The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent PDF

The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent PDF
The Wealth of Humans: Work, Power, and Status in the Twenty-first Century, by Ryan Avent PDF

You Might Also Like

0 komentar